CBS v. ASCAP: An Economic Analysis of a Political Problem
CBS v. A SCAP: An Economic Analysis of a Political Problem
Recommended Citation 0 1
0 Thi s Article is brought to you for free and open access by FLASH: The F ordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. It has been accepted for inclusion in Fordham Law Review by an authorized editor of FLASH: The F ordham Law Archive of Scholarship and History. For more information , please contact
1 John Cirace, CBS v. ASCAP: An Economic Analysis of a Political Problem , 47 Fordham L. Rev. 277 (1978). Available at:
-
INTRODUCTION
C OLUAIBIA BroadcastingSystem, Inc. (CBS) v. American Society
of Composers (ASCAP1) is the culmination of a series of legal
challenges to the marketing of performance rights to musical
compositions. ASCAP and Broadcast Music, Inc. (BIII) 2 have been frequent
targets of antitrust litigation 3 because they control the performance
rights to virtually every domestic copyrighted composition. 4 The most
recent lawsuit attacks the blanket system under which ASCAP and
BMI license these rights to television networks.
It is clear that the fate of the blanket license cannot be determined
by mere reference to legal precedent and economic theory. After nearly
ten years of continual litigation, the issue of its legality remains
unresolved. Analysis of the market structure involved in CBS v.
ASCAP demonstrates why this is so. Neither elimination of the blanket
license nor approval of its present use is appropriate, and the task of
finding a solution between these two extremes that will yield a "fair"
price for musical performance rights is a matter of equity, not of
economics. In a competitive market, price will tend to a competitive
level. In the noncompetitive market of musical performance rights for
network television, however, a competitive price will never emerge,
and there is no economically meaningful method of determining a
competitive price. Thus, the market may be destined for some form of
public regulation.
I.
A HISTORY OF THE CASE
The Copyright Act of 1897 granted composers of music exclusive
rights in the public performance of their works,5 but the task of
* Assistant Professor of Economics. Herbert H. Lehman College of the City UnIversit%of New
York. B.A. 1962, Harvard College; J.D. 1967. Stanford Law School. Ph D. 1975. Columbia
University. The author wishes to thank his colleagues at Lehman College and Professor Donald
Dewey of Columbia University for their helpful cnticism and suggestions
1. 400 F. Supp. 737
(S.D.N.Y. 1975)
, rez,'d, 562 F.2d 130 (2d Cir. 1977). aert granted. C9 S
Ct. 77 (1978) (No. 77-1583).
2. Although this Article focuses on ASCAP, its economic analysis is also applicable to BMI
Emphasis on ASCAP is warranted because ASCAP controls the performance rights to approxi.
mately three-fourths of the domestic copyrighted musical compositions See id at 742
3. See id. at 743-45; Garner, United States v. ASCAP: The Licensing Provisions of tle
Amended FinalJudgment of 1950, 23 Bull. Copyright Soc'y 119 (197,1 Timberg. The Antitnst
Aspects of Merchandising Moden: Music: The ASCAP Consent Judgment of 195, 19 Law &
Contemp. Prob. 294 (1954).
4. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 742.
5. Act of Jan. 6.1897, ch. 4. § 4960. 29 Stat 481 (current version at 17 U S C § 1tt4)(19760
enforcing these rights in theatres, cabarets, hotels, and restaurants
across the country was beyond the capacity of individual composers
and users. 6 ASCAP and BMI were organized as "clearinghouses" for
the buying and selling of nondramatic performance rights in musical
compositions. 7 ASCAP and BMI presently operate as follows:
composers give the clearinghouse nonexclusive authority to license
performance rights to users;8 in turn, the clearinghouse issues to users a
blanket or per program license that allows the use of any or all of the
compositions in the clearinghouse's catalogue for a negotiated fee
which does not vary according to the number of compositions used. 9
When a blanket license is issued, the user pays a fixed percentage of its
total advertising revenues during the period of the license, generally
one year.' 0 When a per program license is issued, the user pays a fixed
percentage of advertising revenues from those programs that actually
use the licensor's music.' 1 Technically, users may also obtain
performance rights directly from composers or their publishers, 12 but this
method is used infrequently, if at all, in the radio and television
industries. 13
Over the years, ASCAP and BMI have supplied musical
performance rights to the radio, television, and motion picture industries.
The blanket licensing system was held illegal with respect to motion
pictures, 14 but it has remained the preferred means of obtaining
performance rights for radio and television. 15 Because such a system
lends itself to abuse, the Department of Justice has negotiated consent
decrees with ASCAP and BMI in an attempt to curtail anticompetitive
practices. ' 6
6. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 741; see Finkelstein, ASCAP as an Example of the Clearing
House System in Operation, 14 Bull. Copyright Soc'y 2, 2 (1966).
7. Finkelstein, supra note 6, at 2.
8. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 741-42.
9. Id. at 742. Individual composers receive distributions from ASCAP's license revenues in
amounts based primarily upon the extent to which their works are performed. United States v.
ASCAP, [1960] Trade Cas. . 69,612 (S.D.N.Y.); Ti-nberg, supra note 3, at 318.
10. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 742.
11. Id.
12. See id. at 754.
13. See id. at 742.
14. See Alden-Rochelle, Inc. v. ASCAP, 80 F. Supp. 888 (S.D.N.Y. 1948).
15. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 742.
16. The Government sued ASCAP and BMI for antitrust violations in 1941. United States v.
ASCAP, [1940-1943] Trade Cas. 56,104 (S.D.N.Y. 19t-1). The complaint charged that the annual
blanket license-the only license then offered-was in restraint of trade. Id. The Government
claimed that the practice of obtaining exclusive licenses from members permitted the exaction of
arbitrary prices from users. Id. The action resulted in a consent decree requiring ASCAP to offer
broadcasters both per program and blanket licenses. Id. at 404. The decree also prohibited ASCAP
from withholding parts of its inventory in order to exact higher prices from users. 1d. at 405.
Finally, ASCAP was enjoined from asserting the exclusive right to license performance rights and
from interfering with individual licensing on the part of its members. Id, at 403. The effectiveness
CBS obtained blanket licenses from ASCAP and BMI for the use of
music in its network programming until 1969, when it challenged the
blanket licensing system. 17 CBS sued ASCAP, BMI, and their
members and affiliates when it reached an impasse in license renewal
negotiations with BMI.' 8 CBS charged that the blanket license
constituted an illegal tie-in and price fixing in violation of section 1 of the
Sherman Act.1 9 It sought an injunction requiring the establishment of
a per use licensing arrangement20 by which a single performance of
each particular musical work would be assigned a reasonable price and
made available to television networks on an individual basis.2 1 In the
alternative, CBS sought an injunction prohibiting blanket licenses for
22
all television networks.
The district court dismissed the complaint. The court found that
CBS was not compelled to enter a blanket license agreement with
either ASCAP or BMI because direct dealing with individual copyright
owners was a viable alternative for the network and CBS failed to
demonstrate any significant obstacles to direct dealing. 23 The court
concluded that the absence of compulsion precluded a finding of a
tie-in or price fixing. 24
On appeal, the Second Circuit reversed. It determined that a
blanket licensing system established by a group of copyright owners
constitutes price fixing in violation of the Sherman Act, 25 and it found
of the last provision as an incentive to composers to engage in direct licensing was undermined by
other provisions in the decree, which permitted ASCAP to compel composers who licensed directly
to pay the royalties derived therefrom into the ASCAP revenue pool. The proceeds were then
distributed to composers at fixed rates. CBS v. ASCAP, 562 F.2d at 133
(citing United States v.
ASCAP, [1940-1943] Trade Cas. at 403)
.
In 1950, the 1941 Decree was amended. United States v. ASCAP, [1950-195 IlTrade Cas. 62,5
95
(S.D.N.Y. 1950
). Under the terms of the amended decree, ASCAP was prohibited from compelling
composers to pay the revenues they received from direct licensing into the ASCAP pool. Id. at
63,752. A provision required that per program licensing be made available to ensure that users
actually had a choice between obtaining a blanket and a per program license. Id. at 63,753-54.
Lastly, a judicial fee-setting procedure was created to be used when ASCAP and a licensee could
not agree upon a negotiated fee. Id. at 63,754.
In 1966, BIIl entered into a similar consent decree with the Government. Pursuant to the terms
of the decree, BMI is required to offer a per program license in addition to a blanket license.
Moreover, differences in the terms of these licenses must be justified by business reasons. See CBS
v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 744.
17. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 753.
18. Id. at 754.
19. 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1976). CBS's complaint also charged a violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act.
Id. § 2. This claim, however, was dismissed by the district court, 400 F. Supp. at 783, and is not
pertinent to the analysis of this Article.
20. 400 F. Supp. at 741.
21. Id. at 747 n.7.
22. Id. at 741.
23. Id. at 757-79.
24. Id. at 780-83.
25. 562 F.2d at 140.
the availability of a viable alternative to blanket licensing, although
dispositive of the tie-in issue, insufficient to overcome the network's
charge of price fixing.2 6 Despite its finding of price fixing, the court
declined to adhere strictly to the per se rule against price fixing-a rule
that technically would require an injunction against the blanket
license.2 7 Instead, in an effort to maintain the advantages of blanket
licensing for the benefit of users of copyrighted musical compositions
other than television networks, the court suggested that blanket
licensing may be a market necessity. 28 The court, however, interpreted the
district court's finding that CBS had the alternative of directly
negotiating with composers as evidence that the blanket licensing
system was not a market necessity in this case. 29
In remanding the case to the district court, the Second Circuit stated
that "if on remand a remedy can be fashioned which will ensure that
the blanket license will not affect the price or negotiations for direct
licenses, the blanket license need not be prohibited in all
circumstances. '30 The court suggested that ASCAP and BMI might be
permitted to continue to offer blanket licenses if the licenses were
found to serve a market need for users and if ASCAP and BMI also
provided an alternative type of license that would augment
competition. 31
II.
ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
The careful opinion of the Second Circuit reveals the perplexities
inherent in CBS v. ASCAP. The court apparently recognized that it
was confronted with an insuperable dilemma, and its intuitive
hesitancy either to outlaw or uphold ASCAP's blanket license is creditable
in light of economic analysis which reveals that either recourse would
encourage anticompetitive activity. 32 Analysis further indicates,
however, that no economic means of effecting competition in this
particular market can be devised. Therefore, any remedy short of public
regulation would be inadequate.
26. Id. at 135, 138.
27. Id. at 140; see United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 221,223-24(1940).
28. 562 F.2d at 136-38, 140 n.26.
29. Id. at 138.
30. Id. at 140.
31. Id.
32. The problem may actually be greater than the Second Circuit envisioned. In a footnote, the
court acknowledged CBS's contention that if the blanket license "overhangs" the market, then the
price of individual performance rights will necessarily be affected, but it stated that on the record it
was not convinced that this is necessarily so. Id. at 140 n.27. The analysis in this Article, however,
leaves no doubt that the existence of a blanket license significantly affects individually negotiated
prices.
ASCAP's Blanket License
In the current market of musical performance rights for network
television, substantial concentration exists on the sides of both buyer
and seller. In general, such a market structure creates a situation
which could favor either the buyer or the seller, depending upon the
bargaining methods employed. In this particular market, however, the
seller will always have the upper hand; a bargaining rule that does not
unduly favor ASCAP cannot be devised.
Until the present time, ASCAP's power to control the market has
presumably been held in check by the fear of adverse judicial reaction
to its practices. If its unrestricted blanket license should receive
judicial sanction, then ASCAP would have free rein to engage in
perfect price discrimination. ASCAP's propensity to do so is aptly
illustrated by its past attempts to use the blanket license as a vehicle
for price discrimination with respect to the radio and motion picture
industries.
1.
Bilateral Monopoly
A bilateral monopoly exists when a single seller, or monopolist,
confronts a single buyer, or monopsonist. The market structure in CBS
v. ASCAP is actually that of a bilateral oligopoly-several sellers
confront several buyers. 33 Nevertheless, analysis of this market in
terms of a bilateral monopoly is valid because ASCAP has substantial
monopoly power and CBS has substantial monopsony power. 34
The relevant market may be analyzed by reference to Figure
1.333. There are two major sellers, ASCAP and BMI, see CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 742,
and three major buyers, CBS, American Broadcasting Company, and the National
Broadcasting Company. See CBS v. ASCAP, 562 F.2d at 132.
34. When there are only two major sellers in a market, those sellers have substantial monopoly
power-the power to raise prices. Any seller whose demand curve is not perfectly elastic has some
monopoly power. J. Robinson, The Economics of Imperfect Competition 4-5 (1934). When there
are only three major buyers, those buyers have substantial monopsony power-the power to lower
prices. Theoretically, buyers have monopsony power even if they can slightly influence price by
changing the amount they purchase in a market. See id. at 216.
At the trial, economist Franklin Fisher, testifying on behalf of CBS, stressed the "cartel" nature
of ASCAP, see Record, vol. 8, at 1653, whereas economist Peter 0. Steiner, testifying on behalf of
ASCAP, stressed the "monopsony" power of CBS. See Record, vol. 15, 4415. This testimony
provides added support for analyzing the market structure in terms of bilateral monopoly. The
added realism afforded by an analysis in terms of bilateral oligopoly would not justify the added
complexity such an analysis would entail.
35. Figure 1 is adapted from M. Friedman. Price Theory 15, Fig. 2.2 t2d ed. 1976). The
demand curve in Figure 1 may be used to analyze any one of the three media: radio, television, or
motion pictures. Musical compositions are fungible in the medium of television. See CBS v.
ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 783. They are, without doubt, at least substantially interchangeable in the
radio and motion picture media. This weaker characterization is sufficient in order to construct an
industry demand curve for the right to perform musical compositions. For example, economists do
o
I_
a
I
0
Demand
Curve
Marginal -o
ReveCnuureve\
_
__
_
__e
E
QUANTITY
For purposes of simplification, the marginal cost to ASCAP of
supplying additional users with performance rights to musical compositions is
assumed to be zero at all relevant quantities. A few remarks will
justify this assumption. First, no one person's hearing or viewing of a
musical performance precludes another from enjoying the same
performance. As such, musical performance rights exhibit the
characteristic of a public good. In contrast to private goods, which may be
consumed by only one person at a time, 3 6 public goods may be
consumed by any number of persons simultaneously. 37 The marginal
cost of additional consumption is zero. In addition, the same musical
composition is often used in the production of sheet music and
phonorecords, as well as in television, radio, and live performances.
Thus, a huge stock of compositions have no economic cost for present
use. The cost of creating them has been incurred in the past, owing to
the demands of users other than network television. The marginal cost
of licensing the performance rights of such compositions to television
networks is zero. 38 It should be noted, however, that the conclusions
not hesitate to discuss the demand for automobiles, even though Volkswagens and Cadillacs are no
more than substantially interchangeable.
36. The classic example of a private good is an apple. C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, Economic
Analysis 399 (rev. ed. 1974).
37. See D. Dewey, Microeconomics 242 (1975); C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, supra note 36, at
399-400; Bator, The Anatomy ofa Market Failure,72 Q.J. Econ. 351 (1958); Head & Shoup, Public
Goods, Private Goods, and Ambiguous Goods, 79 Econ. J. 567, 567 (1969). The paradigm of a
public good is national defense.
38. Only those compositions specially created for television and for which other uses are not
contemplated would have marginal costs of greater than zero. To the extent that musical
compositions are fungible, however, these specially created compositions may be ignored. See note 35
supra.
of this analysis do not rest on the assumption that marginal cost equals
zero. The assumption is made merely to simplify the analysis. 39
One distinctive feature of a bilateral monopoly is that, within that
market structure, price and output are indeterminate. 40 If only one side
of a market is concentrated, price and output can be determined with
reasonable certainty. For instance, a monopolist of performance rights
would maximize his profits by selling at the price and corresponding
quantity at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue. 4 ' Because
marginal cost is zero at all quantities, marginal cost equals marginal
revenue at point E in Figure 1. The monopolist would sell OE units of
performance rights at a price of OA, and his total revenue would equal
OABE. Similarly, the price paid and quantity purchased by a
monopsonist can be ascertained. When sellers compete, the competition causes
price to equal marginal cost, which occurs at point C in Figure 1. In
general, a monopsonist has the power to reduce price below the
competitive level.4 2 Because marginal cost is zero in the market of musical
39. If the reader objects strongly to the assumption that the marginal cost of the right to
perform compositions is zero, a more complicated analysis, which does not require such an
assumption, may be made by superimposing the demand curve of Figure 1over the supply curve of
Figure A at note 42 infra. This analysis yields the same conclusions as the analysis in the text of this
Article.
40. D. Dewey, supra note 37, at 111-13; W. Vickery, Microstatics 115-16 (1964).
41. C. Ferguson, Microeconomic Theory 265 (rev. ed. 1969).
42. This can be illustrated by reference to Figure A below. Assume that DD is the demand
curve of a single buyer, or monopsonist, for labor and that SS is the competitive supply curve for
labor. The competitive equilibrium is at E with a price of IV, and an output of Q1. Optimally, the
monopsonist would like to equate his marginal valuation of the product, given by the demand
curve, with marginal cost, given by the MC curve. He would strive to attain point L, with a price of
W, and an output of Q2. The monopsony price is below the competitive price and fewer workers
are hired. D. Dewey, supra note 37, at 197-99; see C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, supra note 36. at
367-74.
W
0W2
0
D
-D
MC
I
S
I1Li
D
S
Q2Q1
QUANTITY
performance rights for television, however, the competitive price
theoretically would also be zero, and the monopsony price could probably
not be lower. 4 3 Therefore, the monopsonist would buy approximately
OC units at an approximate price of zero. In a bilateral monopoly,
however, neither the monopolist nor the monopsonist can dominate the
other and thereby control the market. The situation is necessarily
indeterminate: the number of units sold will be between OE and OC, and
the price will be between zero, and the monopoly price, OA. 4 4 The
specific result will depend upon the bargaining rules and strategy
45
employed.
In the context of bilateral monopoly, it is extremely difficult to devise
bargaining rules that do not unduly favor one side or the other. 46 The
most commonly used collective bargaining rule in bilateral monopoly
markets permits one side to choose price per unit and the other side to
choose the number of units. 47 The rule generally produces equitable
results, provided that demand is elastic. Labor negotiations in
concentrated industries provide an example of the successful application of this
rule. Labor has a veto power with respect to the level of wages.
Management, on the other hand, usually controls the number of
workers hired. If labor insists on raising the wage rate to a level which is
imprudently high (significantly above the equilibrium level),
management will be forced to reduce the work force, which usually accounts for
a high proportion of total costs. Management can often substitute
machines (capital) for labor, at least in the long run. In short, labor must
consider the effect of its demands upon the number of workers hired. In
terms of economic analysis, at a wage level significantly above the
equilibrium level, the demand for labor becomes elastic, at least in the
long run. 4 8
This rule would fail in negotiations between ASCAP and CBS. The
cost of musical performance rights constitutes less than one percent of
the total cost of an hour-long prime time television show;4 9 thus, CBS
would probably not reduce the number of musical compositions it uses,
43. Conceivably, the competitive price could be negative in that composers might be willing to
pay to have their -compositions performed on television.
44. In a bilateral monopoly, price and output are determinate only if collusion is possible. In
that case, uncertainty surrounds only the division of profit between the monopolist and the
monopsonist. D. Dewey, supra note 37, at 110-13.
45. C. Ferguson, supra note 36, at 281-82. The bilateral monopoly problem can also be
analyzed by means of an Edgeworth box diagram. This approach reaches the same conclusions as
supply and demand analysis, but it highlights the bilateral trading and the indeterminateness of the
solution. See id. at 431-41; W. Vickery, supra note 40, at 115-16. An Edgeworth box diagram will
not be used, however, because it is more cumbersome than supply and demand analysis.
46. W. Vickery, supra note 40, at 116.
47. Id.
48. A. Rees, The Economics of Work and Pay 57-66 (1973).
49. At the time of the trial, CBS paid about $200,000 for an hour-long variety show or dramatic
serial and as much as $750,000 for a made-for-TV movie. Its payments to ASCAP or BMI averaged
about $1,000 per show. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 743.
1978]
even if ASCAP were to double its fees. In short, because the demand for
the right to perform musical compositions is extremely inelastic within
the relevant range of prices, s the labor-management bargaining
procedure would unduly favor ASCAP.
The blanket licensing system also endows ASCAP with the superior
bargaining position in the market of musical performance rights for
network television. In effect, by furnishing a blanket license, ASCAP
chooses both price and quantity. Moreover, it has the power to act as a
discriminating monopolist.
Price Discrimination via the Blanket License
The Discriminating Monopolist
Some discussion is required to explain the term discriminating
monopolist and how the blanket license, in the form of an all-or-nothing
bargain, can enable one to attain this position. In Figure 2, a monopolist
would charge all buyers of performance rights the same price, OA, and
would sell OE units; his revenue is indicated by OABE.5 1 A monopolist
can increase this standard revenue by charging different prices to
different buyers. For instance, some buyers would be willing to pay a price
higher than the monopoly price, OA, but lower than the maximum price
at which a unit could be sold, OD; this is indicated by the DB portion of
the demand curve. If the monopoly price is charged, these buyers will be
able to buy the product for less than they would be willing to pay. The
w
0
D
cc
A
0
(All-or-Nothing
Demand Curve
-Demand
Curve
aB
E
QUANTITY
FIGURE 2
F
C
50. Demand for an input of a final product becomes more inelastic as the proportion of that
input to the total cost of the product decreases. A. Marshall, Principles of Economics 381-93 (8th
ed. 1920); G. Stigler, The Theory of Price 243-44 (3d ed. 1966).
51. See note 41 supra and accompanying text.
(Vol. 4 7
total amount of the benefit is measured by the shaded triangle DAB and
is called consumer surplus. 52 The BC portion of the demand curve
indicates that some buyers would be willing to purchase performance
rights at a price less than the monopoly price. A monopolist who could
charge prices lower than OA to these buyers would capture the revenue
from triangle CEB.
Perfect price discrimination occurs when the monopolist charges each
buyer the maximum amount that he is willing and able to pay.5 3 By
engaging in perfect price discrimination, the discriminating monopolist
is able to appropriate all of the revenue within area DOC, which
comprises the usual monopoly revenue, OABE, consumer surplus,
DAB, and the fruits of a newly created demand, CEB. A monopolist
who wishes to discriminate must be able to determine the demand
elasticities of different buyers and to prevent those who will only pay a
low price from buying its product and selling it to those who will pay a
high price.5 4 If, for example, ASCAP attempted to sell different bundles
of performance rights to different buyers at different prices, it would
confront the difficult problem of determining how much each buyer is
willing to pay for each bundle of rights.
This problem can be avoided by using an all-or-nothing bargain, or
blanket license, under which a buyer must purchase either a specified
quantity or nothing at all.55 Whereas competitive dealing presupposes
that buyers are free to purchase either the maximum number of units
available or a smaller quantity at a corresponding price, the
all-ornothing bargain forces a buyer to purchase more units than he wishes to
purchase at a price that is higher than he wishes to pay. The
all-ornothing demand curve in Figure 2 demonstrates that the all-or-nothing
bargain yields the same revenue as perfect price discrimination. 5 6 If
buyers are collectively given a choice of buying either OC units at an
average price of OA per unit or nothing, then the total revenue from
such sale is OAFC. Because triangle DAB is equal to triangle FCB, the
total revenue from the all-or-nothing bargain, OAFC, is equal to the
total revenue of the discriminating monopolist, DOC.5 7 Thus, the
allor-nothing bargain allows the monopolist to reap the benefits of perfect
price discrimination without confronting the problems posed by dealing
with different buyers on different terms.
ASCAP's Attempts at Price Discrimination
Since price discrimination would be most advantageous for ASCAP,
it is likely that ASCAP would exploit its availability, given the
oppor52. See C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, supra note 36, at 127-29.
53. J. Robinson, supra note 34, at 187 n.1; see W. Vickery, supra note 40, at 104-05.
54. W. Vickery, supra note 40, at 294-97.
55. It should be noted here that, in the context of the all-or-nothing blanket license, the
marginal cost to the buyer, CBS, of the right to perform an additional composition is zero.
56. See M. Friedman, supra note 35, at 15 n.l.
57. See notes 53-54 supra and accompanying text.
tunity to do so. This presumption is supported by ASCAP's historical
proclivity to use the all-or-nothing bargain as a.,vehicle for price
discrimination. Moreover, the history of ASCAP's discriminatory activities
reveals that ASCAP retains the potential to engage in such activities
with respect to the network television industry.
i. ASCAP and the Radio Industry: In about 1920, ASCAP realized
that the radio industry held commercial possibilities.5" It began to issue
blanket licenses free, or at nominal fees, to fledgling radio stations.5 9
ASCAP steadily increased its fees and during the 1930's raised its
prices 900%.60 In 1932, ASCAP and the radio stations entered a
contract by which each station was to be charged a flat fee plus 2% of its
gross advertising revenue in 1933, 4% in 1934, and 5% in 1935. The
contract in force in 1935 was extended for five years. 61 At this time, fees
were charged only to individual stations and not to national
broadcast6 2
ing networks.
62. Id. at 395. During this period of rising license fees, the radio industry, under the leadership
of the National Association of Broadcasters, unsuccessfully challenged ASCAP in several ways. It
sought repeal of the statutory minimum damage provision for infringement of a musical copyright,
which provided for damages of $250 for each and every infringement. Copyright Act, ch. 356, §
25(b), 37 Stat. 489 (1912) (current version at 17 U.S.C. § 101(b) (1976)). This provision was a
powerful deterrent, given the great difficulty in proving actual damage from a broadcast copyright
infringement. See Comment, Revision of the Copyright Law, 51 Harv. L. Rev. 906 (1938);
Comment, Copyright Reform and the Duffy Bill, 47 Yale L.J. 433 (1938).
The radio industry also enlisted the aid of state legislation. As a result, many states passed
legislation prohibiting the blanket license or placing a tax on ASCAP's compositions. E.g., Act of
Feb. 16, 1939, ch. 13, 1939 Alaska Sess. Laws 66 (current version at Alaska Stat. §§ 45.50.330-.460
(1962)); Act of June 12, 1939, ch. 19653, 1939-1 Fla. Laws 1575 (repealed 1977); Act of June 10,
1937, ch. 17807, 1937-1 Fla. Laws 204 (repealed 1977); Act of lay 17, 1937, ch. 138, 1937 Neb.
Laws 488 (current version at Neb. Rev. Stat. §§ 59-1401 to 1406 (1974)); Copyright Act, ch. 115,
1939 N.D. Sess. Laws 160 (current version at N.D. Cent. Code §§ 47-21-01 to 11 (1978)); Act of
May 18, 1937, ch. 212, 1937 Tenn. Pub. Acts 828 (repealed 1943); Act of Apr. 13, 1939, No. 32,
1939 Vt. Acts 46 (current version at Vt. Stat. Ann. tit. 32, §§ 7901-7904 (1970)); Act of Mar. 8,
1937, ch. 218, 1937 Wash. Laws 1070 (current version at Wash. Rev. Code Ann. §§ 19.24.010-.900
(1978)); see Cohn, supra note 60, at 416-19; Note, Anti-ASCAP Legislation and Its Judicial
Interpretation,9 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 713 (1941) [hereinafter cited as Anti-ASCAP Legislation),
note, Musical Monopolies and Legislative Control,53 Harv. L. Rev. 458 (1940) [hereinafter cited
as MusicalMonopolies]. Several of these laws were held unconstitutional. See Buck v. Harton, 33
F. Supp. 1014 (M.D. Tenn. 1940); Buck v. Swanson, 33 F. Supp. 377
(D. Neb. 1939)
, rev'd on
other grounds sub nom. March v. Buck, 313 U.S. 406 (1931); cf. Buck v. Gallagher, 307 U.S. 95
(1939) (ASCAP has standing to request injunction against enforcement of Washington anti-ASCAP
statute); Gibbs v. Buck, 307 U.S. 66 (1939) (same with respect to Florida statute).
This history indicates that, from its inception, ASCAP exhibited a
tendency to discriminate in price. A license fee based upon a percentage
of gross revenue is discriminatory in that. it grants the same number of
rights to different licensees for different total dollar amounts, depending
upon their ability to pay. The effectiveness of price discrimination is
significantly enhanced by the all-or-nothing blanket license. 63
By 1939, ASCAP derived two-thirds of its revenue from radio license
fees. 64 In that year, it served notice that it intended to charge blanket
license fees according to the source of the program. This change in
licensing would have doubled the fees paid by radio from over four
million dollars to eight or nine million dollars. For the first time, ASCAP
also sought fees from the networks; it proposed to charge them .7.5% of
their gross advertising revenue. Local stations were offered either a
reduction or no change in fee, depending upon the size of the station. 65
ASCAP's proposal was similar to one that would be made by a
discriminating monopolist. It would have resulted in significantly
different rates for different licensees. ASCAP proposed to charge one rate
to small stations, a higher rate to medium size stations, a still higher rate
to large stations, and the highest rate to networks. 66 Assuming that the
revenue ASCAP received from the radio industry prior to its proposal
approached the normal monopoly revenue, OABE in Figure 2, the
proposed system would yield an amount approximating the
discriminating monopolist's revenue, DOC.
The radio industry refused to accede to ASCAP's demands. The
National Association of Broadcasters formed a rival performing rights
society, BMI, and the nation's radio stations commenced a ten-month
boycott of ASCAP's music. 67 In addition, the Government revived
a dormant antitrust suit 68 and filed a criminal prosecution against
ASCAP. 69 In 1941, as a result of these hostile reactions, ASCAP
compromised. It contracted with the networks and individual stations
1978]
for a fixed percentage of their gross advertising revenues, 70 and it
entered into a consent decree with the Government. 7'
The consent decree, however, placed ineffectual restraints on ASCAP
and had no significant impact on subsequent negotiations. 2 The first
provision of the decree stated that ASCAP could not acquire exclusive
performance rights from its members; yet, it authorized ASCAP to
collect all proceeds that its members derived from individual contracts
with users. 73 Therefore, because copyright owners had no incentive to
deal as individuals, all prices were, in effect, the product of collective
bargaining.
The second provision prohibited ASCAP from entering into "any
performing license agreement which shall result in discriminating in
price or terms between licensees similarly situated; provided, however,
that differentials based upon applicable business factors which justify
different prices or terms shall not be considered discrimination . . . . 7
This provision is vacuous because price discrimination is only profitable
when the licensees are not similarly situated. If licensees are similarly
situated, the price that will afford ASCAP the greatest profit from one is
the same as that for the other. In terms of economic analysis, price
discrimination is profitable only when different buyers have dissimilar
elasticities of demand. 75
The decree also required ASCAP to offer a per program license, in
addition to an annual blanket license, and to set a per unit price for
musical compositions. ASCAP was also prohibited from charging
license fees for programs during which no music is played and from
requiring additional licenses for stations that broadcast programs
provided by the networks. 76 These provisions of the consent decree were
also ineffectual. A license fee represents only a small fraction of the total
cost of a program, and therefore it is unlikely that the fee, however
computed, would have a substantial impact on the number of musical
70. The contracts ran through 1949 and were automatically renewable unless a party objected.
Id. at 172.
71. United States v. ASCAP, [1940-19431 Trade Cas. 56,104
(S.D.N.Y. 1941)
. The terms of
the consent decree are discussed at note 16 supra. The consent decree also provided for some
reforms within the ASCAP organization which are not relevant to this discussion. See (1940-19431
Trade Cas. at 405.
72. This befits a consent decree signed within one week of the filing of the complaint. See
Garner, supra note 3, at 124.
73. The decree stated: ASCAP "shall not . . .assert any exclusive performing right . . .on
behalf of any copyright owner. . . .Nothing herein contained shall be construed as preventing
[ASCAP]... from... requiring all moneys derived from the issuance of licenses by the respective
members of [ASCAP] to be paid by the licensee to [ASCAP] and distributed in the same manner as
other revenues." United States v. ASCAP, [1940-19431 Trade Cas r 56,104, at 403
(S.D.N.Y.
1941)
.
74. Id.
75. W. Vickery, supra note 40, at 294-97.
76. United States v. ASCAP, [1940-1943] Trade Cas. ,56,104, at 404-05
(S.D.N.Y. 1941)
.
compositions broadcasted. 77 Given several methods for determining
prices, ASCAP could use the method most favorable to it and merely
adjust the prices derived by any other method so as either to generate
the same revenue or make such methods unattractive. For example, per
program licensing can be structured to provide ASCAP with the same
revenue as blanket licensing. Assuming that musical compositions are
performed on one-half of a station's programs and the rate for a blanket
license is two percent of gross advertising revenue,7 8 a fee of four
percent of advertising revenue from programs on which musical
compositions are performed, which would approximate the blanket license
fee, could be charged instead. The ineffectiveness of a per program
alternative is borne out by the general lack of interest in per program
licenses. 79 Similarly, the price of per piece licensing could be set to make
that alternative unattractive. Because price discrimination in the
context of the blanket license is most favorable to ASCAP, other bargaining
methods, which would ordinarily be less favorable, are not
economically relevant if price discrimination is not limited or prohibited.
ii. ASCAP and the Motion Picture Industry: In 1946, ASCAP
wished to increase its revenue from the motion picture industry. The
rates for that industry were set in fixed dollar terms that had not been
changed since 1933.80 Pursuant to a contract due to expire in 1947, each
motion picture exhibitor paid an annual license fee that was computed
according to the number of its theatre seats: ten cents per seat for
theatres with less than 800 seats, fifteen cents per seat for theatres with
800 to 1599 seats, and twenty cents per seat for theatres with more than
1,600 seats. 8 1 ASCAP proposed to abandon this formula and to charge,
77. Performance license fees were 5% or less of radio station's gross advertising revenue; thus,
the demand for those rights was inelastic. See note 50 supra.
78. In 1947, the blanket annual rate for a radio station was 2.5% of advertising revenue and the
per program rate was 8% of a program's revenue. Variety, Sept. 17, 1947, at 46, col. 4. The
commercial blanket license in radio has since been reduced to 1.725% of a station's net receipts
from sponsors. Garner, supra note 3, at 138-39. The current blanket license for local television
stations consists of a threshold fee of 2% of net receipts for a given year, plus a decreasing
percentage for receipts in excess of the threshold level. Ihe per program license fee is 9% of net
receipts for most programs; for motion pictures shown on television, however, the fee is 4%.
Record vol. 20, at E300, CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. 737
(S.D.N.Y. 1975)
; Garner, supra note
3, at 147.
79. "The per program license ... has fallen into disuse .... The current disparity between the
per program and blanket license has led some observers to conclude that licensees have been
deprived of the 'economic choice' contemplated by the 1950 Judgment." Garner, supra note 3, at
138-39 (footnote omitted).
80. Film Daily, March 28, 1947, at 1, col. 3; Motion Picture Daily, March 24, 1947, at 1,col. 4.
81. Variety, Apr. 23, 1947, at 38, col. 1. "From 1918-19, when ASCAP first began to collect
from the exhibitor, to 1925, there had been a theoretical fee of 5 cents per seat per annum, collected
first only in New York City and then, gradually and bitterly fought, in the exchange centers, When
the 1925 flat fee collapsed under the weight of exhibitors' protests, a sliding scale, based on the
theatre's seating capacity, was instituted in 1935." Motion Picture Herald, Feb. 21, 1948, at 16.
This formula contained a modest amount of price discrimination. Nevertheless, it was probably
less discriminatory than a system whereby exhibitors pay a given percentage of their gross
revenue.
instead, an annual fee in the dollar amount that the licensee would
collect at top adult prices from a single performance at full capacity in
his theatre.8 2 The change would have resulted in a 200% increase in
total fees 3-an increase magnified by the 60% rise in the consumer
price index during the 1933-1946 period.8 4 The increase was not to be
distributed uniformly among the exhibitors; approximately 9,000 of the
16,000 theatres would have paid only a slight increase in dollar or
percentage terms, while the impact on the larger first-run theatres
would have been much greater.8 5
ASCAP's proposed formula was similar to one in which each theatre
would pay the same percentage of gross revenue.8 6 This method of
computing license fees involves some price discrimination but is not
usually regarded as an unfair method of determining prices. In the
context of the all-or-nothing bargain, however, the discriminatory
impact is augmented.8 7
Motion picture exhibitors strenuously resisted the proposal,8 8 and a
majority of exhibitors organized the Theatre Owners of America to
represent them in negotiations with ASCAP.8 9 Confronted with such
opposition, ASCAP capitulated and stipulated to a twenty-five percent
increase in license fees for large theatres, a slight increase for medium
size theatres, and no increase for small theatres. 90 Despite this
agreement, some exhibitors continued to fight any "seat tax," 9 ' and they
brought private antitrust actions against ASCAP. In two of these cases,
ASCAP was adjudged to have violated the antitrust laws. 92 One court
stated that "[a]lmost every part of the Ascap structure, almost all of
Ascap's activities in licensing motion picture theatres, involve a
violation of the anti-trust laws" 93 and held that theatre owners were no
longer required to pay license fees. 94
In 1950, as a result of ASCAP's dealings with the motion picture
industry, the consent decree was amended. 95 The amended judgment
prohibited ASCAP from licensing performance rights to motion picture
exhibitors. 96 It provided that licenses be issued on a "per film" basis and
not on an "industry-wide" basis. 97 Consequently, a system that
bypassed ASCAP evolved; individual motion picture producers began to
bargain directly with individual copyright owners.or their publishers.9 8
The 1950 amended judgment restructured the licensing system for the
motion picture industry only. No restriction was placed on ASCAP's
ability to use the blanket license with respect to radio and television, nor
was any attempt made to formulate a rule for determining fees under a
blanket license that would reduce ASCAP's power to engage in price
discrimination. 9 9 Thus, ASCAP retains the power to discriminate in
price with respect to the network television industry. Given ASCAP's
historical proclivity to do so if afforded the opportunity, it seems likely
that an unqualified judicial sanction of ASCAP's present blanket
licensing system would spur such anticompetitive activity.
B.
Prohibitionof the Blanket License
A prohibition of ASCAP's blanket license is as unacceptable as the
preservation of the license in its present form. Although a number of
commentators have opposed an injunction against the blanket license on
1978]
CBS
the ground that the transaction costs of direct bargaining between CBS
and individual composers or their publishers would be prohibitive, 0 0
this is not a valid criticism. Such costs do not present an insurmountable
barrier to direct licensing. Nevertheless, direct licensing of musical
performance rights in the context of network television would be
economically unsound. The principal objection to direct licensing is that if
copyright owners were forced to deal with CBS on an individual basis,
then CBS could assert its monopsony power over those individuals.
If radio stations were to contract directly with individual copyright
owners for musical performance rights, then the number of separate
contracts between individual stations and individual copyright owners
would be counted in the millions, each involving small dollar
amounts. '0 ' Thus, the radio industry needs a blanket license to keep the
number of individual contracts and their costs at manageable levels. In
contrast, the motion picture industry has successfully dispensed with the
blanket license; it has developed a market "machinery" by which motion
picture producers bargain directly with individual composers for
performance rights. 10 2 In CBS v. ASCAP, the district court found that the
market machinery that exists in the motion picture industry could easily
be expanded to accommodate the television industry.' 0 3 In effect, the
court found that the television networks' use of music was more like the
motion picture industry's than the radio industry's' 04 and that direct
100. See 91 Harv. L. Rev. 488, 493-495 (1977) [hereinafter cited as Middleman]; Comment,
CBS v. ASCAP: PerformingRights Societies andthe PerSeRule, 87 Yale L J. 783, 786-787 (1978)
[hereinafter cited as Performing Rights Societies].
In order to support this theory, the Harvard commentator analogizes ASCAP to a middleman.
This analogy, however, is inappropriate. The best example of middlemen are wholesalers, who
typically deal in competitive markets. CBS v. ASCAP involves bilateral monopoly power. See
ptII(A)(1) supra. A bilateral monopoly functions quite differently from a competitive market, and
operations in one cannot necessarily be attributed to the other. Moreover, the middleman analog'
does not comport with principles of agency law. The Harvard commentator confuses the definitions
of broker and middleman. See Middleman,supra, at 492 n.27. In the law of agency, middlemen do
not negotiate on behalf of either party; they are essentially finders who bring parties together and
therefore can receive payments from both. Brokers, on the other hand, have a fiduciary duty to
bargain on behalf of the part), they represent, their principal, and can only accept payment from
that party to the transaction. See F. Mechem, Outlines of the Law of Agency §§ 501, 503 (4th ed P.
Mechem 1952). See also Spratlin, Harrington & Thomas, Inc. v. Hawn, 116 Ga. App. 175, 156
S.E.2d 402 (1967). Thus, in terms of agency law, ASCAP more closely resembles a broker than a
middleman.
101. See Performing Rights Societies, supra note 100, at 786.
102. CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp at 759-60.
103. Id. at 757-65.
104. Television programs are mainly made-for-TV movies or video taped shows, each of which
uses a limited number of musical compositions. Id. at 755-56.
licensing to network television program producers by copyright owners
was feasible.' 05
The district court's reasoning is valid. The CBS network nationally
telecasts approximately 7,500 programs annually. 10 6 Its music
requirements consist chiefly of "inside" music, that is, theme and background
music specifically composed for a particular program. "Outside" music,
which consists primarily of feature music and some background music
that has been composed previously, is used regularly on only a small
number of programs' 0 7 and accounts for only about ten to fifteen
percent of CBS's present music needs.' 8
Producers hold the rights to inside music composed for their
programs; they must obtain the rights to outside music from the composer
or his representative. Most of the programs broadcasted over the CBS
television network are produced by independent production companies
referred to as "program packagers."' 0 9 At present, the program
packagers do not provide CBS with performance rights to music. They do,
however, furnish many other rights that CBS needs in order to
broadcast copyrighted music, such as the right to record a composition in
synchronization with the film or video tape. 1 0 "Synch" rights are not
provided by means of a blanket license, and the process by which these
rights are licensed could also be used to license performance rights.
Program packagers obtain their synchronization rights in one of two
ways, depending upon the type of music involved. With respect to
inside music, many packagers own publishing subsidiaries that acquire
the copyrights directly from the composers. " The district court
observed that these publishers maintain catalogues of the compositions
they control and found that CBS could feasibly negotiate with them for
performance rights, as it does for synchronization rights. 1 2 With
respect to outside music, synchronization rights for packagers are almost
exclusively brokered through the Harry Fox Agency, Inc. (Fox Agency),
which represents virtually every major music publisher. The Fox
Agency issues several thousand television synchronization licenses
annually. 1 13 In addition,. the Fox Agency handles the motion picture
105. Id. at 765.
106. Id. at 742.
107. Outside music is used on "variety shows and variety specials, sports shows (e.g., football
halftime shows), late night talk shows, and the 'Captain Kangaroo Show.' " Id. at 756.
108. Id. at 757.
109. Id. at 755. Most of the prime time serials fall into this category. At the time of the trial,
CBS itself produced only "Gunsmoke," two daytime serials, and some variety, news, public affairs,
and sports programs. Id. at 742.
110. Id. at 759.
111. Id. at 756. With respect to performance rights, ASCAP distributes royalties to these
subsidiaries for music performed on shows created by their parent companies. Id.
112. Id. at 760-61.
113. Id. at 759-60. "Because Fox has instructions regarding each publisher's fee structure, (or,
more often, is familiar with it on the basis of past experience) it is usually able to quote prices over
industry's "movie rights" contracts, which provide for package coverage
of both synchronization and performance rights for theatrical motion
pictures. 114 The district court concluded that television producers could
similarly license performance rights through the Fox Agency or a new
agency modeled on it."15
Therefore, if the blanket license is eliminated, a workable system of
licensing performance rights could nevertheless be developed. "1 6 CBS v.
ASCAP presents the case for ASCAP's blanket license unclouded by the
issue of transaction costs.
The Monopsony Power of Network Television
Although transaction costs would not preclude individual bargaining,
a more significant economic consideration supports the maintenance of
some form of blanket licensing. The substantial concentration on the
buyers' side of the market indicates that the networks have monopsony
power in the market for musical performance rights.1 17 In addition, two
factors indicate that substantial concentration may be inherent in the
network television industry. I 8 First, the cost of producing prime time
the telephone for the compositions which interest the producer. The entire transaction, including
actual issuance of the license, is completed within two to three days at most" Id. at 760.
114. Id. The combined synchronization-performance right package sells for between $250 and
$20,000 per composition per motion picture, and the price is not often below $750. Record, vol. 5,
at 846. In contrast, synchronization rights for use in television sell at very low rates. The usual price
range is $50 to $150 per composition; $250 is considered a high price. Id. at 817-20. There was
testimony that if it were not for "nuisance value," the price of synchronization rights for television
would be zero in many instances. Id., vol. 8, at 1677-79. One reason given for accepting a low price
in television was that copyright owners want their compositions performed on television. Id., vol. 5,
at 814. Composers may believe that television performances of their music will increase their sales
in other media. In addition, they may believe that ASCAP's collective power with respect to
performance rights insures that their distributions from ASCAP exceed the amounts they would
receive if they sold combined synchronization and performance rights as individuals. See id. at 927.
The monopsony power of the network may contribute to the low price as well.
115. Id. at 762.
116. The district court's finding that direct licensing of performance rights is feasible was
accepted by the Second Circuit. 562 F.2d at 134-40.
117. See notes 33-34 supra and accompanying text.
118. An argument against this contention can be advanced on the ground that removal of the
restrictions on competition between pay television and "free," or advertiser-sponsored television,
by charging a price to all television viewers would alter the pattern of substantial concentration in
the industry. Free television plans its programming to attract the largest audience possible, but
such programming fails to consider differences in preferences and intensity of demand. If a price
were charged to television viewers, then diverse preferences would have to be taken into account.
The current mass audience, a precondition for advertising revenue, would become fragmented, and
fewer viewers would be needed to spon-or a particular program. Therefore, it would be possible for
competitors to arise and enter the market. It is not possible to predict whether removing the
restrictions against such competition would reduce the substantial concentration in the network
television industry. Lower and middle income families, however, have a strong interest in the
present system of free television. R. Noll, M. Peck & J. Mc Gowan, Economic Aspects of Television
Regulation at 32-33 (1973) [hereinafter cited as R. Noll]. Changes that significantly alter the existing
market structure would probably not be politically acceptable.
network shows is extremely high,' ' 9 and only a few networks are able to
generate the capital needed to support such shows. 120 Second, network
television exhibits some aspects of a natural monopoly.
The critical indicator of the existence of a natural monopoly is an
inherent tendency to decreasing unit cots1 2' as output increases, 22
From the perspective of the viewer, network television broadcasting
exhibits this characteristic of a natural monopoly. 123 An additional
viewer does not increase a network's total cost; marginal cost equals
zero. Cost per viewer, therefore, declines indefinitely as more viewers
watch the network. From the perspective of the network, however, unit
costs do not necessarily decrease as output increases. 124 If a network can
attract additional viewers only by spending more money on programs,
then its marginal cost per added viewer is greater than zero.
Broadcasters would spend to increase audience size only to the point at which
advertising revenue from an additional viewer equals the cost of
attracting the viewer. From this standpoint, network television broadcasting
may not be a natural monopoly. Nevertheless, the fact that average
cost decreases from one perspective and increases from another does not
necessarily preclude the possibility that network television is a natural
monopoly. In practice, natural monopolies are difficult to identify, and
many industries that are widely recognized as natural monopolies
exhibit the same ambiguous cost and output pattern as network television.
For example, a local telephone company is generally considered a
natural monopoly. If output is measured by the number of messages, unit
costs decline as output increases because the cost of transmitting an
additional message is minimal. On the other hand, if output is measured
by the number of subscribers, unit costs increase because the number of
connections in the central exchange increases more than proportionately
119. See note 49 supra and accompanying text.
120. The three national networks provide most of the prime time programs shown on television
and a majority of all programs broadcasted by affiliated stations. Most local television stations are
affiliated with one of the three networks. R. Noll, supra note 118, at 15.
121. Several different meanings may be applied to the term "decreasing unit costs." (1)
Short-run decreasing costs: When a firm has a given existing capacity, total unit cost of production
declines as output increases, up to the physical limits of the capacity of the firm's operations. (2)
Long-run decreasing unit costs: As a firm increases its capacity, unit costs decrease, provided that
the additional capacity is fully utilized. This phenomenon as due to economies of scale internal to
the firm. The natural monopoly concept is related to this definition. (3) Decreasing costs due to
economies of scale external to the firm: As an entire industry grows it may acquire some of its inputs
at decreasing average costs, because its growth enables the suppliers of those inputs to take
advantage of potential economies of scale internal to their industry. (4) Decreasing costs over time
as a result of technological progress. I A. Kahn, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and
Institutions 124-30 (1970); C. Phillips, The Economics of Regulation 22 (1969).
122. 2 A. Kahn, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions 119 (1971).
123. G. Becker, Economic Theory 95 (1971); R. Noll, supra note 118, at 33.
124. See R. Noll, supra note 118, at 10-11.
as the number of subscribers increases.' 25
Even if network television is not a natural monopoly, however, the
actual concentration in the industry would enable the networks to
reduce the price of musical performance rights below the competitive
level. 126 Competition among individual copyright owners to sell musical
performance rights to networks would, in itself, cause the price of such
rights to decline. The monopsony or buying power of the networks
would place further downward pressure on the price. In short, if
individual copyright owners were required to negotiate with the television
networks or their program producers, bargaining power would be
overwhelmingly with the networks.
No system short of blanket licensing will adequately offset the
monopsony power of network television. For instance, a "per use"
system, such as that suggested by CBS, would decidedly favor the buyer
over the seller. Under such a system, CBS would bargain with
individual copyright owners, and ASCAP would maintain a "per use reservoir"
for use in the event that an individual composer could not be
contacted. 127 The price of each performance right licensed from ASCAP
would be determined after considering the nature of the use, duration of
the use, and popularity of the composition. 28
At the trial in CBS v. ASCAP, the level to which the price of
compositions in the per use reservoir would tend was a source of
disagreement. Peter 0. Steiner, economist for ASCAP, claimed that the
per use price would be a ceiling price because CBS could assert its
monopsony power over many copyright owners and would use the per
use reservoir only when it lacked such power.' 2 9 Franklin Fisher,
economist for CBS, claimed that the per use reservoir price would
125. 1 A. Kahn, supra note 121, at 125.
126. See note 42 supra and accompanying text.
127. See CBS v. ASCAP, 400 F. Supp. at 747 n.7.
128. Id. Other telecasters have proposed systems similar to that suggested by CBS. In United
States v. ASCAP, [1971] Trade Cas. , 73,491 (S.D.N.Y.), the National Broadcasting Company
(NBC) requested a license for 2,217 ASCAP compositions which were the most frequently featured
performances on its variety shows. NBC intended to obtain the remainder of its music
requirements through direct transactions. Id. at 90,008-09. In United States v. ASCAP, 208 F. Supp. 896
(S.D.N.Y. 1962), appealdismissed per curiam sub nora. Shenandoah Valley Broadcasting, Inc. v.
ASCAP, 371 U.S. 540, appealdismissed, 317 F.2d 90 (2d Cir.), rev'd, 375 U.S. 39 (1963), modified,
375 U.S. 994, aff'd, 331 F.2d 117 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 377 U.S. 997 (1964), over 300 local
television stations that paid for music on all nonnetwork programs they broadcasted wanted a
license that would exclude all independently produced prerecorded programs. Individual producers
of television programs would have obtained licenses for rights to the music performed on the shows
they produced. Therefore, the local stations would have paid only for performances on locally
produced programs. The court denied the request and stated that the stations wanted a license that
was neither a blanket license nor a per program license but "a composite sort of license, containing
a little bit of both." Id. at 897.
129. Record, vol. 15, at 4415.
reflect supply and demand and therefore would be self-correcting. He
claimed that if the price were too high, most transactions would take
place outside the reservoir, and that if it were too low, most would take
place within the reservoir. 130 When called to the witness stand a second
time, however, Fisher correctly stated that a resolution of the dispute
depended upon whether musical compositions are fungible,13 1 If they
are fungible, CBS would be able to coerce a composer to lower his
individual price by threatening to use another composer's music
instead.1 32 Because CBS could usually obtain a lower price from the
composer himself, it would rarely have to resort to the per use reservoir.
Given the district court's conclusion that musical compositions are
fungible in the medium of television, Steiner's claim that the per use
reservoir would set a ceiling price that CBS would use only if it could
not assert its monopsony power appears to be correct. Thus, a per use
system would not mitigate the monopsony problem presented by direct
licensing.
C.
Summarv
Neither ASCAP's present blanket licensing system nor compulsory
individual contracting between television networks and composers
establishes economically acceptable bargaining rules in the market for
musical performance rights. If ASCAP were to continue to bargain
without restriction on behalf of copyright owners, then price would tend
to the monopoly price, which is higher than a competitive price. If
copyright owners were to deal directly with CBS, then price would tend
to the monopsony price, which is lower than a competitive price.
An attempt to avoid the monopoly-monopsony problem by asking
what the price of musical performing rights would be if the market
structure were theoretically competitive would fail. According to the
theory of perfect competition, a product's price is efficient if it equals the
cost of producing an additional unit, that is, marginal cost. 133 In the
context of this theory, it is difficult to determine a price for products
such as musical compositions which, once created, are costless to use.
Because an additional performance is costless to the composer, the
efficient price of musical performance rights is zero.
Some economists believe that decisions concerning how many of these
goods to produce and who should produce them are best left to the
130. Id., vol. 8, at 1660.
131. Id., vol. 16, at 4769-70.
132. At the trial, witnesses often used "Happy Birthday" as an example of a song that is not
fungible. A producer of television programs testified, however, that as a reasonable substitute one
could sing "For He's a Jolly Good Fellow," have a cake with candies on stage, and have someone
blow out the candles. Id., vol. 4, at 603-04 (testimony of Edward Duke Vincent).
133. C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, supra note 36, at 393-94; Bator, The Simple Analytics of
Welfare Maximization, 47 Am. Econ. Rev. 22 (1957).
political process. They suggest that such goods be provided to the public
free of charge, that payment be made indirectly through a general
increase in taxes, and that the producers of such public goods be
subsidized by the government. 134 The results of such a solution, however,
would reflect neither a perfectly competitive or efficient price nor a fair
or just financial return for composers. Nevertheless, because there is no
economically meaningful method of determining a price between the
monopoly and monopsony prices, and because a collective bargaining
rule that would be equitable to both CBS and ASCAP does not exist,
some form of public regulation is necessary.
LEGISLATING A PRICE
Although license fees should be regulated, the basic blanket licensing
structure should be retained. That structure is necessary to offset the
monopsony power of the television networks. Moreover, the blanket
license has served the television industry satisfactorily for over thirty
years. 135 Its value as a convenient means of licensing musical
performance rights is undeniable, and although transaction costs would not
preclude individual dealing, 13 6 the blanket license certainly reduces
such costs. 137 The courts have recognized the virtues of the blanket
license, 138 and in the past they have employed tortuous reasoning in
order to avoid barring its use.' 39 Public regulation of the blanket
license, in the form of a court-imposed fee or a quasi-regulatory price,
would eliminate the need to resort to such evasive devices, as well as
prevent the television networks from asserting their monopsony power
over individual composers.
Fashioning a rule for collective selling that will fairly adjust the
relationship between CBS and ASCAP necessarily entails a policy
decision, because no suitable price for performance rights can be determined
economically. 140 This decision may, of course, be made by Congress.
Alternatively, in this case it may be made by the courts. The authority
to make such a decision, however, does not aid in determining a
particular method that will provide desirable results. Therefore, some
suggestions are made as to viable means of regulating fees under a
blanket license.
A.
CongressionalRegulation
The very existence of composers' performance rights is the result of a
political decision embodied in the Copyright Act of 1897.141 In fact, the
copyright laws contain many politically determined provisions that
represent marked deviations from the market system. For instance, the
pricing of the uses of musical compositions is controlled in various ways;
markets are combined for the sale of sheet music, 142 and the right to
make phonorecords is publicly regulated. 143 Thus, congressional
regulation in the area of composers' rights is not unprecedented.
It is particularly noteworthy that, although it did not address musical
performance rights with respect to commercial television, the Copyright
Law of 1976144 directed a method for pricing such rights in
noncommercial television. This method provides for collective bargaining, with
judicial determination of a price should the parties fail to agree. 14
Similar legislation could be directed to musical performances on
commercial network television. Such a provision would probably be more
reasonable than subsidizing composers, an action that would permit
their compositions to be performed free of charge. 146
The responsibility for formulating a method of determining an
appropriate license fee need not be left to Congress. The courts may develop
and impose such a rule by exercising their authority under the 1950
amended judgment or by finding that ASCAP's activities constitute a
market failure and, as such, warrant exceptional remedial
consideration.
Occasionally, competitive markets will not efficiently allocate
resources with respect to particular products. There are three possible
141. See note 5 supra and accompanying text.
142. 17 U.S.C. app. § 106 (1976).
143. Id. §§ 115, 801.
144. 17 U.S.C. app. §§ 101-810 (1976).
145. Id. app. § 118 (1976).
146. Finkelstein, The Composer and the Public Interest-Regulation of Performing Right
Societies, 19 Law & Contemp. Prob. 275, 292 (1954); Reasonable Compromise, supra note 59, at
277. Such legislative regulation would properly be conducted by the Copyright Royal Tribunal. See
17 U.S.C. app. § 801 (1976).
reasons for such a market failure: natural monopoly, public good, and
ownership externality. 147 When market failures occur, nonmarket
solutions may be necessary. This fact has been recognized by courts which,
when confronted with certain market failures, have imposed regulatory
measures for remedying anticompetitive effects. 14 8 To date, such cases
have involved only the market failure of natural monopoly.
In United States v. Terminal Railroad Association, 4 9 several
railroads that crossed the Mississippi River organized an association which
acquired control of available bridges and terminal facilities. The
facilities clearly exhibited the characteristic of a natural monopoly. As
more people use bridge and terminal facilities, the costs per person
decline. 150 An ordinary application of the antitrust laws in this case
would have resulted in the dissolution of the association. The Supreme
Court, however, fashioned a remedy to meet the particular
circumstances. Instead of ordering dissolution, the Court required that all
railroads be given the opportunity to use the facilities on equal terms. t5 '
functioning exception. The Chicago Board of Trade was a grain market whose members were
brokers, commission merchants, millers, manufacturers of corn products, and grain elevator
owners. The Board adopted a rule that required those buying and selling grain outside of trading
hours to do so at the price at which the market closed. The rule was held not to violate the antitrust
laws. 246 U.S. at 239-41.
Another often cited case in this area is Appalachian Coals, Inc. v. United States. 288 U-& 344
(1933), which created an exception to the per se rule against price fixing. It is widely recognized,
however, that this exception was developed under the severe conditions of the Great Depression
and is without precedential value. In that case, 137 companies, producing 12% of the bituminous
coal mined east of the Mississippi River and 74% of that mined in the Appalachian territory, had
set up a joint agency to handle all their sales. The Supreme Court recognized that the arrangement
established common prices for the firms involved, but then discussed the depressed state of the
industry: "[The industry] suffered from over-expansion and from a serious relative decline through
the growing use of substitute fuels. It was afflicted by injurious practices within itself,-practices
which demanded correction.... When industry is grievously hurt, when producing concerns fail,
when unemployment mounts and communities dependent upon profitable production are
prostrated, the wells of commerce go dry." Id. at 372. The Court noted that the combination did not
have a sufficient market share to be able to fix the market price. Moreover, any increase in the price
of coal promised to reopen numerous mines previously shut down by low prices. The Court allowed
the arrangement to stand but took the precaution of having the district court retain jurisdiction for
further proceedings if future developments should justify that course. "Appalachian Coals is often
regarded today as an aberration of the nineteen thirties, when competition was often
deemphasized." P. Areeda, Antitrust Analysis 357 (2d ed. 1974).
149. 224 U.S. 383 (1912), modified, 236 U.S. 194 (1915).
150. Cf. 2 A. Kahn, supra note 122, at 125 (analysis of municipal water supply which may be
analogized to bridge and terminal facilities). See generally United States v. Terminal R.R_ Ass'n,
224 U.S. at 397-98.
224 U.S. at 411-12.
Similarly, in Associated Press v. United States, 152 the Court framed
an equitable remedy without imposing the full sanctions of the antitrust
laws. The Associated Press distributed news gathered by its own
employees, its member newspapers, and foreign news agencies to its
members. The news gathering activity displayed the primary characteristic
of natural monopoly: the collaborative activity caused unit costs to
decrease as output increased. 153 The Court, however, did not enjoin
this activity. Instead, it held that members of such combinations must
anfofnodrdisccroimmipneattiotorrys taecrcmesss. 1t5o4 the news gathered by the combination on
ASCAP's activities also have a natural monopoly aspect. ASCAP was
organized to finance a staff of "musical police" who, in order to detect
copyright infringements, would investigate establishments in which
music was played. 15 5 On a national scale, this activity is clearly beyond
the capability of an individual or a small group. 156 The larger the group,
the lower the cost of this policing activity will be per person. Thus, the
infringement detection activity displays a tendency to decreasing unit
costs as output increases. Although this activity is not directly in issue in
CBS v. ASCAP, it can be used as a basis for applying the market failure
exception to the antitrust laws, thereby enabling ASCAP to continue its
activities as regulated by the courts.
In addition, ASCAP's infringement detection activity is related to the
two other types of market failure. The activity is necessary because of
the public good aspect of musical compositions. It is difficult to devise a
market mechanism for excluding those who do not pay for a public
good. If individuals cannot be excluded, they receive a "free ride" when
the good is provided to others. 15 7 This excludability problem
necessitates ASCAP's infringement detection activities.
The infringement detection activity is also related to an ownership
externality. This type of market failure exists when the owner of a
resource or product has no legally enforceable right to charge a price for
its use or abuse. A determination as to who should bear the costs of such
externalities toften requires an adjustment of legal rights or
governmental intercession.15 8 For example, a homeowner incurs the cost of more
frequent house painting by virtue of his residing near a factory that
emits smoke. If a law is passed that prohibits factory owners from
polluting, or requires them to pay a tax related to the amount of damage
done, then the cost of cleaning the air will be included in the price of the
factory's product and will be paid for by consumers. In such a case, the
market externality is internalized.1 5 9
Prior to the enactment of the Copyright Law of 1897, there was an
ownership externality with respect to musical performance rights;
musical compositions could legally be performed without compensating the
composer. 160 The law, which granted musical performance rights, is an
example of a legal adjustment which made possible the internalization
of an externality. The externality was not removed for practical
purposes, however, until ASCAP's formation. Ownership externalities
involving large groups of individuals require at least quasi-governmental
regulation such as ASCAP's infringement detection activity in addition
to an alteration of legal rights. 16 1
ASCAP's infringement activity, therefore, exhibits characteristics of
all three types of market failure. The courts could rely on any one of
these market failures to fashion a remedy that would eliminate
anticompetitive effects while preserving ASCAP's valuable activities. Although
there are no cases that explicitly recognize the public good or ownership
externality failures as meriting such exceptional treatment, if any
market failure exists, appropriate regulation should be available.
Competition via markets can hardly be demanded when markets fail.
The 1950 amended judgment to the 1941 consent decree contains a
provision for judicial determination of a reasonable price for musical
performance rights, should ASCAP and a customer fail to agree. 162 The
court has never exercised its power under this provision but has
preferred to act merely as a mediator. 163 The provision, however, assumes
more significance than it has been accorded in light of an economic
analysis of the market involved; it provides a means of setting a fair
price in a situation that precludes the emergence of such a price from
natural market forces.
Given the wide range of possible prices in bilateral monopoly
bargaining, the court, if it did set a price, would probably choose the historical
price with minor adjustments. Interim prices, which the court also has
the power to set, 164 have been set in this manner.'16 In view of the
higher than competitive rate of profit that the television networks have
enjoyed,1 66 a rule that each network should pay ASCAP the historical
rate of 2% to 2.5% of its gross advertising revenue is not
unreasonable. 167 This method of determining blanket license fees, which contains
some price discrimination, 168 would permit ASCAP to share in the
networks' higher than competitive profit. Recent contracts between
CBS and ASCAP, however, have provided for a flat license fee. 169 That
such a flat fee is more favorable to CBS than a fee based on a percentage
of gross advertising revenue should be considered by a court that
intends to use such an historical price in setting a fee for the blanket
license.
C.
Suggested Methods of Regulation
The use of an historical rate to ascertain a suitable license fee is only
one method that the courts and legislature could employ. Other viable
options are suggested below. Before any additional suggestions are
made, however, the lack of an indisputably correct solution should be
reiterated. In addition, it is important that only one collective selling
rule be adopted. If more than one rule is allowed, as in the consent
decrees,' 70 ASCAP could set the price according to the terms most
favorable to it, and the prices under the other rules could be adjusted so
as to make them unattractive.
One system of regulating ASCAP's blanket license fees could be to set
one flat fee for all television networks. This system would prevent
ASCAP from discriminating in price among the different networks. If it
is considered desirable to restrict ASCAP's revenue, the fee could be
based upon a percentage of the revenue of the financially weakest
network. This procedure would reduce the total amount collected in
1978]
license fees below what it would be if each network were charged a
certain percentage of its own revenue.
Another possible option would be to prohibit the annual blanket
license and to permit blanket licensing only on a per program basis.
Different license fees could be charged for different types of programs,
and the fees could reflect either an historical price or a percentage of the
revenue of the least affluent network. Under this procedure, networks
that use the most music would tend to pay the highest fees.
Because of the difficulty in assessing composers' investment and
opportunity costs, a true regulatory price for musical compositions could
probably not be determined. For most regulated industries, such as
public utilities, price is set so that revenue will cover current costs,
replace depreciated capital, and earn a fair return on invested
capital.1 71 An accurate estimate of the amount of money and time invested
and an appraisal of a fair rate of return are crucial to this procedure.
The investment in creating musical compositions, however, cannot be
estimated accurately. There is no recognized skill or educational level
that is required for or common to all composers. Moreover, the time that
it takes to create a piece of music varies among composers and
compositions; there are child prodigies like Mozart, composers who devote all of
their time to their work, composers who also work as conductors or
musicians, and so on. Even if the investment could be assessed,
however, a fair rate of return, or opportunity cost, for composers could
probably not be gauged because of the difference in quality and
popularity of various musical compositions. All that can be said is that, if a
regulatory price is set for musical compositions, whatever that price
may be, it will probably not affect the overall rate of return for
composers. If there is free entry into the market, a higher price will cause an
increase in total investment and the number of compositions produced,
but since demand is inelastic, the same number of compositions will be
sold, and competition will force the rate of return on total investment to
the equilibrium rate. 172
Although a suitable price cannot be ascertained by application of
standard regulatory procedures, a quasi-regulatory price can be
determined by reference to prices for musical performance rights in the
motion picture industry. The use of music on television is similar to that
in motion pictures, with two provisos: the monopsony power of network
television does not appear to be shared by motion picture producers,
and although musical compositions are fungible in the television
medium, they may or may not be fungible in the motion picture industry.
Notwithstanding these provisos, the average price of musical
perfor171. See generally 1 A. Kahn, supra note 121, at 76131; C. Phillips, supra note 121, at 260.302;
C. Wilcox & W. Shepherd, Public Policies Toward Business 359-90 (Sth ed. 1975).
172. See generally D. Dewey, Modern Capital Theory 79-92 (1965).
mance rights in the motion picture industry could be determined, and
that price could be carried over to the television industry. Either a single
average price for combined synchronization and performance rights or
several average prices for various types or uses of music could be
calculated.
This procedure should not be used prospectively because of the
danger that future prices in the motion picture industry might be
influenced by composers' knowledge tha. the same prices would be used
in the television industry. Composers could demand higher prices in
their dealings with motion picture producers and attempt to recoup any
losses incurred by a decrease in sales through higher fees in the
television industry. Nevertheless, the twenty-five years of past price
experience in the motion picture industry could serve as the basis for
determining fees for network television. The historical fees could then be
adjusted to reflect intervening changes in the cost of living. Such a
quasiregulatory procedure would provide a feasible means of setting
reasonable license fees for television networks.
CONCLUSION
Introducing public regulation into the musical performance rights
market may arouse justifiable consternation. Governmental
intervention in the economic realm has traditionally been regarded with
suspicion and disfavor; the efficient prices of perfect competition are
considered secondary to the operation of natural market forces. 173 The
realities of the market structure involved in CBS v. ASCAP, however,
preclude reliance on natural market forces to produce a price that even
approaches a competitive level. To counteract ASCAP's current
bargaining power with compulsory direct dealing between composers and
networks would merely shift the balance of power from the monopolistic
to the monopsonistic extreme. The impossibility of determining an
economically meaningful price between these extremes compels recourse
to regulatory measures. A price that will not unfairly exploit either side
of the market must rest on equitable considerations. 174
173. See M. Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom 7-36 (1962).
174. Although the judiciary is empowered to set a price for musical performance rights, Its
determination of a fee would necessarily entail a political decision. This political decision Is within
the domain of the legislature and, therefore, will probably necessitate an amendment to the
copyright laws.
58. See generally Caldwell, The Copyright Problems of Broadcasters , 2 J. Radio L. 287 , 292 ( 1932 ).
59. Comment , ASCAP and the Antitrust Laws: The Story of a Reasonable Compromise, 1959 Duke L .J. 258 , 262 [hereinafter cited as Reasonable Compromise].
60. Allen , The Battle of Tin Pan Alley , 181 Harpers 514, 519 ( 1940 ). ASCAP defended its constantly rising license fees by arguing that performances on radio drastically reduced the sales of sheet music; it reasoned that radio is a substitute product for sheet music and that the wide exposure and constant repetition of a melody shortened the life of a musical composition . Cohn, Music, Radio Broadcasters and the Sherman Act , 29 Geo. L.J. 407 , 413 ( 1941 ).
61. Mills & Miller, The ASCAP-NAB Controversy:The Issues, 11 Air L . Rev . 394 , 399 ( 1940 ).
63. See notes 56- 57 supra and accompanying text. In several suits during the 1930's, however, ASCAP's price discrimination was held not to violate the antitrust laws . Buck v. Del Papa , 17 F. Supp . 645 (D.R.I . 1937 ); Buck v . Hillsgrove Country Club , Inc., 17 F. Supp . 643 (D.R.I . 1937 ).
64. Allen , supra note 60, at 515.
65. Mills & Miller, supra note 61, at 396- 402 . With respect to local stations, ASCAP proposed license fee redutions of 50% for the smallest and financially weakest stations, 33V3% reductions for medium size stations, and neither reductions nor increases for large stations . Id.
66. See note 65 supra and accompanying text .
67. White , Musical Copyrightsv. the Anti-trust Laws , 30 Neb. L. Rev. 50 , 54 ( 1951 ) ; Comment, Music CopyrightAssociations and the AntitrustLaws, 25 Ind. L.J. 168 , 172 ( 1950 ) [hereinafter cited as Music Copyright Associations] .
68. In the early 1940's, commentators were divided on the question whether ASCAP wits In violation of federal antitrust laws . See, e.g., Cohen, Stare Regulation of Musical Copyright , 18 Ore. L. Rev. 175 ( 1939 ) (pro-ASCAP); Cohn, supra note 60 (same); Note, ASCAP and the Sherman Act, 12 Air L . Rev . 173 ( 1941 ) (same); AnU'-ASCAP Legislation, supra note 62 (suspicious of ASCAP); Musical Monopolies , supra note' 62 (same).
69. ASCAP pleaded nolo contendere to the charges and was fined $ 35 , 250 . Music Copyright Associations, supra note 67 , at 178-79.
82. Film Daily , Aug. 22 , 1947 , at 1, col. 2; Hollywood Rep ., Aug . 22 , 1947 , at 1,col. 4. There was to be a 15% discount for exhibitors who had 70 to 100 performances per month, and a 30,% discount for those with less than 70 performances per month. Because the average number of performances was 80 per month, most theatres would qualify for the 15% discount. In addition, ticket taxes were to be excluded from the computation of the fee . Variety, Sept. 3 , 1947 , at 4, col. 4. See generally Motion Picture Daily, Sept. 8 , 1947 , at 2, col. 2.
83. License fees were expected to roughly triple from $1.3 million to $4.5 million. This would represent a 200% increase, but the trade papers referred to it as a 300% increase . Motion Picture Daily, Aug. 25 , 1947 , at 1, col. 4; Motion Picture Daily , Aug. 22 , 1947 , at 1, col. 3; Motion Picture Herald , Aug. 30 , 1947 , at 17; Variety, Aug. 27 , 1947 , at 5, col. 3.
84. U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Historical Statistics of the United States 210-11 ( 1975 ) ; Motion Picture Daily , Aug. 25 , 1947 , at 1, col. 4. Moreover, the proposed increase came at a time when exhibitors were experiencing a 15-20% attendance decline from the peak levels of 1946 . Variety, Oct. 1 , 1947 , at 16, col. 4.
85. Motion Picture Herald, Aug. 30 , 1947 , at 17. For example, Radio City Music Hall, which paid $1,240 under the old formula, would have paid $7,279 under the proposal . Motion Picture Daily, Aug. 26 , 1947 , at 6, col. 4.
86. "Wemerely ascertain the potential income from a capacity sale of the theatre for a single performance, and use that as the amount of the annual license fee. Since there are usually well over 1,000 performances a year, it is simple mathematics to estimate that the society will receive about one-one-thousandth of each admission dollar . " Hollywood Rep ., Aug . 22 , 1947 , at 9, col. 2 (quoting Deems Taylor , President of ASCAP).
87. See notes 56-57 supra and accompanying text.
88. Timberg , supra note 3, at 299-305.
89. Motion Picture Herald, Sept. 27 , 1947 , at 1.
90. Motion Picture Daily, Feb. 9 , 1948 , at 1, col. 1; Motion Picture Herald , Feb. 14 , 1948 , at 21; Variety, Feb. 11 , 1948 , at 4, col. 5.
91. Film Daily , Feb. 18 , 1948 , at 1, col. 1.
92. M. Witmark & Sons v. Jensen , 80 F. Supp . 843 ( D. Minn . 1948 ), appeal dismissed mDem . sub nor. M. Witmark & Sons v. Berger Amusement Co., 177 F.2d 515 ( 8th Cir . 1949 ) ; AldenRochelle, Inc . v. ASCAP , 80 F. Supp . 888 (S.D.N .Y 1948 ).
93. Alden-Rochelle , Inc. v. ASCAP , 80 F. Supp . 1388 , 893 (S.D.N .Y. 1948 ).
94. Id . at 900.
95. See United States v . ASCAP, [ 1950 -1951] Trade Cas . 62 , 595 (S.D.N .Y. 1950 ). This judgment did little more than conform to the decision in Alden-Rochelle, Inc . v. ASCAP , 80 F. Supp . 888 (S.D.N .Y. 1948 ).
96. United States v . ASCAP, [ 1950 -1951] Trade Cas . 62 , 595 , at 63 , 752 (S.D.N .Y. 1950 ).
97. Id . at 63 , 753 .
98. Record , vol. 5 , at 824-27, CBS v. ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . 737 (S.D.N .Y. 1975 ) (testimony of Albert Berman, Managing Director of the Harry Fox Agency) .
99. Although the consent decrees prohibited ASCAP fTom acquiring exclusive licenses from its members, composers have little incentive to bargain individually. The bargaining power of even the most famous composer does not approach the collective bargaining power available to ASCAP through the all-or-nothing bargain. The all-or-nothing bargain also removes any incentive for users to deal with individual composers. Users would obtain blanket licenses, if available, and therefore would not pay twice for the use of the same compositions . See CBS v. ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . at 754. 1.
134. See , e.g., D. Dewey, supra.note 37, at 216-19; C. Ferguson &S. Maurice, supra note 36, at 399-400; Hotelling, The Relation ofPrices to MarginalCosts in an Optimum System, 7 Econometrica 151 , 151 - 55 , 158 - 60 ( 1939 ).
135. CBS v. ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . at 742.
136. See pt. l(B) ( 1) supra .
137. See Performing Rights Societies, supra note 100 , at 786.
138. See , e.g., CBS v . ASCAP , 562 F.2d at 140; CBS v. ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . at 742.
139. Prior to CBS v. ASCAP, the courts uniformly rejected attacks on the blanket license . See, e.g., Sam Fox Publishing Co. v. United States , 366 U.S. 683 ( 1961 ) (third parties have no standing to modify a consent decree); K-91 , Inc. v. Gershwin Publishing Corp., 372 F.2d I (9th Cir . 1967 ) (ASCAP is insulated by the consent decree because the district court is the final arbiter of price tinder the decree), cert . denied, 389 U.S. 1045 ( 1968 ) ; United States v . ASCAP , 341 F.2d 1003 ( Zd Cir. ) (same), cert . denied, 382 U.S. 877 ( 1965 ) ; United States v . ASCAP, [1971] Trade Cas .
73 , 491 (S.D.N .Y.) (twenty years of acquiescence in the interpretation of the 1950 amended judgment is conclusive).
140. See pt. 1I(C) supra .
147. See W. Nicholson , Microeconomic Theory 425-529 ( 1972 ).
148. See Associated Press v. United States , 326 U.S. 1 ( 1945 ); Chicago Bd. of Trade v. United States , 246 U.S. 231 ( 1918 ) ; United States v . Terminal R.R. Ass'n, 224 U.S. 383 ( 1912 ), modified, 236 U.S. 194 ( 1915 ). It is noteworthy that both CBS and the Government recognized such an exception . See CBS v. ASCAP , 562 F.2d at 136 - 37 . Chicago Board ofTrade involved a true market
152. 326 U.S. 1 ( 1945 ).
153. See generally id . at 13 n.10.
154. Id . at 21.
155. Allen , supra note 60, at 516 , 521 . The battle in the courts to stop the piracy of musical compositions was long and costly . See Herbert v. Shanley Co., 242 U.S. 591 ( 1917 ) ; Dreamland Ball Room, Inc . v. Shapiro, Bernstein & Co., 36 F.2d 354 ( 7th Cir . 1929 ); Irving Berlin, Inc. v. Daigle, 31 F.2d 832 ( 5th Cir . 1929 ); Pastime Amusement Co . v. M. Witmark & Sons, 2 F.Zd 1020 ( 4th Cir . 1924 ); M. Witmark & Sons v. Calloway , 22 F. 2d 412 (E.D. Tenn . 1927 ); Harms v . Cohen , 279 F. 276 (E.D. Pa . 1922 ); Hubbell v . Royal Pastime Amusement Co., 242 F . 1002 (S.D.N .Y. 1917 ) ; 174th St. & Saint Nicholas Ave . Amusement Co. v. Maxwell , 169 N.Y.S. 895 ( Sup. Ct . 1918 ).
156. Cohn, supra note 60, at 410.
157. C. Ferguson & S. Maurice, supra note 36, at 399-400.
158. D. Dewey, supra note 37, at 224.
159. E.J. Mishan , Cost-Benefit Analysis 109- 62 (2d ed. 1976 ).
160. The story of how Stephen Foster died nearly penniless in a New York hospital is a graphic, if extreme, illustration of the effects of an ownership externality . See 5 , 000 ,000 Songs, 7 Fortune 27, 32 ( 1933 ).
161. In this respect, large group externalities are distinguishable from small group externalities . See generally Coase , The Problem of Social Cost , 3 J.L. & Econ . 1 ( 1960 ) ; Regan, The Problem of Social Cost Revisited, 15 J.L. & Econ . 427 ( 1972 ).
162. United States v . ASCAP, [ 1950 -1951] Trade Cas . 62 , 595 , at 63 , 754 (S.D.N .Y. 1950 ).
163. Garner , supra note 3, at 127-28.
164. United States v . ASCAP, [ 1950 -1951] Trade Cas . 62 , 595 , at 63 , 754 (S.D.N .Y. 1950 ).
165. See Garner, supra note 3 , at 147.
166. See R. Noll , supra note 118, at 16-17.
167. During the 1958 -1961 period, the network license fee was 2.5% of net receipts from sponsors, after deductions , plus $12 . 50 per month per affiliated station . Record , vol. 23 , at E1051-52, CBS v. ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . 737 (S.D.N .Y. 1975 ).
168. See note 63 supra and accompanying text .
169. For the period 1962-1963, the district court temporarily continued the agreement then in effect . Record , vol. 23 , at El133 , CBS v . ASCAP , 400 F. Supp . 737 (S.D.N .Y. 1975 ). In 1964, the license fee was reduced 20% with respect to receipts in excess of 1963 receipts . Id. at E 1133- 34 . The fee for 1965 was subject to agreement; $4,505,000 was pidd . Id. , vol. 20 , at ES . The license fee has been a negotiated flat fee since 1966 . Id. at ES; id., vol. 23 , at E1135.
170. See notes 76-79 supra and accompanying text.